Wednesday, November 07, 2007

ECB, After Hard Birth, Comes of Age in Crisis

ECB, After Hard Birth,
Comes of Age in Crisis

Europe Bank Gets Points
For First-Response Role;
War Games in Frankfurt
By JOELLEN PERRY, WSJ, Nov 6, 2007.

FRANKFURT -- At 12:32 p.m. on Thursday, Aug. 9, just past its ninth birthday, the European Central Bank grew up.

The summer's mounting financial crisis, sparked by rising defaults on U.S. subprime mortgages, had fully crossed the Atlantic that morning. European banks feared their counterparts were exposed to risky investments linked to these mortgages, and became unusually reluctant to lend to each other. Financial institutions were paralyzed.

[Jean-Claude Trichet]

Tasked with stopping such a meltdown was the European Central Bank, which sets monetary policy for 13 countries from Ireland to Greece. The institution has been dogged since inception by criticisms that it valued consensus over decisiveness. Early on, it had been called slow-footed, disorganized and prone to miscommunicating its intentions.

But that day, the ECB swooped to the rescue. The bank offered unlimited overnight loans at its policy rate of 4%. By day's end, it had lent €94.8 billion -- about $131 billion -- which was more than it had put into money markets the day after Sept. 11, 2001. The first response by a major central bank to the summer's crisis, it stunned markets for its size. It also surprised counterparts at the U.S. Federal Reserve, who followed the ECB's injection with a smaller $24 billion one of their own later that day.

Observers credit the ECB and its head, Jean-Claude Trichet, with making a trenchant decision that calmed markets. The move shored up confidence in the bank's ability to keep markets functioning for the U.S. dollar's most significant rival. With its boosted credibility, the ECB could enhance the euro's standing in world markets. Continued confidence in the currency could ultimately come at the expense of the dollar, the current favorite of big world investors thanks in part to the size, liquidity and stability of U.S. markets.

"There were always worries that the ECB would be a stereotypical European institution, slow to decide and going off in multiple directions at once," says Adam Posen of the Peterson Institute for International Economics, a Washington think tank. "Mr. Trichet has put that to rest in this situation."

The ECB now faces fresh challenges. Global stock markets are swooning as the credit-market fallout deepens, with big write-downs and CEO departures at Citigroup Inc. and Merrill Lynch & Co. spurring fears that other banks could post more big losses. European bank shares fell yesterday, helping to bring down major indexes. And, as in the U.S. and United Kingdom, the gap between the rates euro-zone institutions charge each other for longer-term loans and the ECB's target rate remains unusually wide, suggesting markets remain tense.

A FORMER BANKER COMMENTS
"When 9/11 happened, there was some skepticism that we weren't prepared, because we were too new. We knew we could do it, but we had no track record. I think the ECB has done a perfect job."
-- Read more from former ECB board member Otmar Issing's interview with The Wall Street Journal.

This complicates the picture for ECB policy makers, who meet Thursday. Prior to the summer's credit-market unrest, robust euro-zone growth had the bank set for at least one more interest-rate rise this year. Now policy makers are caught between worries that inflation pressures are building, while the economy has yet to feel the full effect of credit-market turmoil, bank-sector write-offs and the euro's surge. In contrast to the Fed, which has cut rates by 3/4 of a percentage point since September, the ECB is likely to keep its key rate on hold Thursday. Investors see a protracted pause, but some policy makers have said the rate still could rise.

A portrait of the ECB's August response to the financial crisis emerges from documents, public statements and people familiar with the bank's workings. The ECB had been primed for a liquidity lockup, running Pentagon-style war games with such scenarios as early as April 2005. Its president, long-time French central banker Mr. Trichet, had warned loudly that investors were underestimating the danger of risky holdings. After market tremors earlier in the summer, ECB staffers who monitor markets were on high alert.

Some observers criticized the ECB for inciting panic with its intervention, saying the scope of its response suggested the bank was bracing for a catastrophe. A few still say the ECB overreacted, arguing that the offer of unlimited funds at the ECB's target rate -- the central-bank equivalent of a fire sale -- rewarded the type of risky investments that spurred the subprime debacle to start with.

The ECB still has vulnerabilities, of course, as separate events over the past three months have demonstrated. A communication gaffe by the bank left financial markets confused for days in mid-August about whether the ECB intended to raise rates. A fragmented system of bank supervision left it without detailed information about bank balance sheets at a moment of crisis. And it faces persistent sniping from politicians as it refuses to restrain a rise in the euro on foreign-exchange markets that is provoking yelps from some exporters.

Derided From Start

The ECB was established on June 1, 1998. Critics derided the institution as unworkable from the start. To shore up credibility, the ECB modeled itself after Germany's inflation-phobic Bundesbank. Like the U.S. Federal Reserve, the ECB sets a target for interest rates on overnight loans between banks. But unlike the Fed, whose dual mandate makes it attentive to both inflation and growth, the ECB's prime focus is on keeping prices stable. It aims to keep inflation at just under 2% in the 13 countries that now share the euro currency.

The ECB's rate-setting body includes the six members of its Executive Board, who oversee the bank's day-to-day operations, plus the 13 heads of the euro-zone's national central banks. Rather than voting on interest-rate decisions and publishing the minutes of their meetings, as Fed officials do, the ECB's 19 Governing Council members make decisions by consensus. The bank explains its thinking in a news conference after each decision.

The euro debuted with fanfare, and an initial value of $1.17, in 1999. Although the ECB's primary focus is inflation, not the exchange rate, a falling currency can be read as a market vote of no-confidence in an economy and its managers. Over the next 22 months, amid scattershot communication from ECB policy makers, the euro deteriorated to 83 cents.

The bank's now-deceased first president, Wim Duisenberg, initially reinforced the perception of disorganization. Although he had been an accomplished former Dutch central-bank head, the lanky policy maker with a mop of white hair became known at the ECB for a colloquial candor, uncommon in central-banking circles, that repeatedly steered markets the wrong way. British tabloids dubbed him "Dim Wim."

War Games

Since late 2003, the ECB's public face has been Mr. Trichet. A poetry buff who studied economics and mining engineering, the 64-year-old Mr. Trichet is long on practical experience, from the French Treasury to the World Bank. He was president of the Paris Club of creditor nations from 1985 to 1993, an era in which Latin American, African and Russian debts were restructured, and head of the French central bank for a decade.

By 2005, the ECB was preparing for potential market chaos. That April, at its 37-story glass-and-metal headquarters in Frankfurt, 65 participants spent two and half days in exercises aimed at honing their response to a future crisis. About a year later, some 150 people took part in a conference from their home countries to play out shocks to the financial system. In 40 teleconference calls over half a week, the group responded to various scenarios, including a prescient case in which banks sought emergency loans but policy makers didn't know whether the banks were solvent. Top policy makers were barraged by rumors, sometimes contradictory, and by actors playing inquisitive journalists.

The real thing arrived this summer. For months, U.S. homeowners with subprime mortgages -- high-interest loans extended to high-risk borrowers -- had been defaulting in rising numbers. Investors who had bought opaque securities backed by these mortgages ran into trouble as the securities became difficult to value and thus potentially hard to trade.

By late July, there were mounting clues that continental European banks were vulnerable. On July 27, the little-known German IKB Deutsche Industriebank AG revealed it had major exposure to the U.S. subprime-mortgage market, prompting an emergency weekend €3.5 billion bailout organized by Germany's financial regulator, with contributions from major German banks.

Markets lurched into early August. Even as European business slowed for vacation, the ECB's team of market monitors -- usually about 15 people, whittled to around a dozen because of vacations -- was on alert. Working on the second floor of the bank's high-rise, the team watches everything from global stock-exchange movements to copper prices.

Some five members of the team monitor money-market rates, the interest banks charge each other for loans. In the afternoon of Tuesday, Aug. 7, rates on loans ranging from overnight to a year started rising. This was puzzling: Just that morning, the ECB had conducted its regular weekly refinancing operations. That should have provided banks with enough cash to last them the week -- and, by extension, kept the rates between banks relatively flat.

In phone calls with the market monitors, commercial bank treasurers confirmed their banks were antsy.

Wednesday brought more jitters. Though the ECB had set its target rate at 4%, overnight money-market rates continued rising above that. Investors were fleeing to havens such as two-year German government bonds. Data showed commercial banks' reserves with the central bank had fallen, another sign that banks might be hoarding cash.

U.S. VS. EURO ZONE
Projected 2007 GDP*:
U.S.: $13.794 trillion
Euro zone: $11.905 trillion
Unemployment:
U.S.: 4.7% (October)
Euro zone: 7.3% (September)
Consumer prices, growth from year earlier:
U.S.: 2.8% (September)
Euro zone: 2.6% (October)
Current account deficit as % of GDP, second quarter:
U.S.: 5.5%
Euro zone: 0.1%
Population, 2006
U.S.: 299.4 million
Euro zone: 316.7 million**
*Converted to U.S. dollars at current rate.
**Includes population of Slovenia, admitted to the euro zone Jan. 1, 2007.
Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook database, Eurostat, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Commerce Department, U.S. Census

By Wednesday evening, staffers had suggested that the six-member Executive Board consider taking the unusual step of injecting cash to restore calm. By then, Mr. Trichet and Lucas Papademos, the ECB's vice president, were in touch with U.S. Fed governors.

The ECB prefers to stage major interventions before noon, when commercial-bank treasurers are sure to be at their desks. The bank decided to wait until the morning and act if markets were still tense.

They were. At 8:30 a.m. on Thursday, Aug. 9, major French bank BNP Paribas announced it was suspending withdrawals from three investment funds because it couldn't value them amid the subprime crisis. Rumors flew that other banks were in trouble.

"I've never experienced anything like it," says Christoph Rieger, interest-rate strategist at Dresdner Kleinwort in Frankfurt. The fear "ground the market to a halt."

Extraordinary Tension

Interest rates on overnight loans between European banks soared. Typically, market monitors snap to attention if the overnight rate moves a few hundredths of a point away from the bank's policy rate. Now, rates hit 4.7%, far above the ECB's 4% target, signaling extraordinary tension.

Convening at 8:45 a.m., the ECB liquidity group decided to recommend intervening that morning and taking the unprecedented step of pre-announcing that the bank would honor every bid it received. To send a clear signal that the bank was covering the market's back, the committee settled on offering funds at the bank's 4% policy rate rather than a variable rate or a higher penalty rate. Taken together, the moves would show the ECB just how high the demand for cash was, because banks, in principle, would bid for exactly what they felt they needed. The ECB could use the information to judge future injections more accurately.

The six Executive Board members approved the move within 90 minutes.

At 10:26 a.m., the bank told markets it stood "ready to act." At 12:32 p.m., it flashed its decision on trading screens across the euro zone. The notice said the ECB would accept bids for funds until 1:05 p.m. Response was immediate. At 2 p.m., the ECB publicized the total take of €94.8 billion. The overnight rate fell back down to around 4%. In subsequent days and weeks, the ECB continued to add funds to money markets to keep the market liquid.

But challenges continued to arise, in part because the ECB doesn't have detailed insight into the euro zone's banks. While the Fed effectively supervises most of the biggest U.S. banks and has access to detailed information on these banks' books, the ECB cedes banking supervision to each member country.

Days after its Aug. 9 fund injection, the central bank sent commercial-bank supervisors across the euro zone a questionnaire asking about their subprime exposure. The basic question: Were banks basically sound and just having a problem with short-term liquidity? Or were some of them in deeper trouble?

Some responses were returned quickly and fully. Others came back late or without sufficient numbers. In the end, the ECB learned enough to be confident that banks were sound. But some people in and out of the ECB are unsure that the bank would get the information it needs in a bigger crisis.

[Euro's Ups and Downs]

In the following weeks, another old ECB problem resurfaced -- communicating intentions clearly to the market. Mr. Trichet had been getting high marks for predictability, but that changed on Aug. 22.

On the back of the ECB's continuing cash injections, overnight lending rates had fallen back to around the 4% target. But three-month interbank rates still hovered around 4.7%, a sign that banks were reluctant to lend to each other for longer periods.

At 3:34 p.m. that day, the ECB released a surprise statement saying it would hold an auction the following day, accepting bids for €40 billion in extra three-month funds. Markets greeted the announcement with relief. But the statement's last sentence caused confusion. "The position of the Governing Council of the ECB on its monetary policy stance was expressed by its president on 2 August 2007," it read.

That was a reference to a briefing held by Mr. Trichet weeks earlier, at which he indicated that the bank, at the time, was inclined to raise short-term rates at its next meeting on Sept. 6. In the intervening turmoil, however, markets had steadily revised down expectations of an ECB interest-rate rise. The late August statement seemed to put a hike back in play.

"To say markets didn't know how to interpret it is putting it mildly," says Dresdner Kleinwort's Mr. Rieger.

Crossed Signals

The communication problem was compounded two days later, on Aug. 24. Anonymous sources at several national central banks leaked word to Reuters that markets had misinterpreted the sentence about the ECB's monetary-policy intentions: ECB policy makers were not set on raising rates. Speaking in Budapest a few days later, Mr. Trichet intervened to clarify the message, essentially telling markets that policy makers hadn't decided whether to move rates.

On Sept. 6, the bank kept its policy rate unchanged at 4%.

Observers say that while the bank proved its chops with its early August moves, it still has room to master the subtle art of communicating its intent. "It's as important as moving rates well," says Luigi Buttiglione, a former Bank of Italy economist, now with New York-based investment fund Fortress Investment Group in London, who praised the August intervention. "You not only have to do the right thing, but you have to explain why this is the right thing. If you're not able to do that, then markets can take a different direction -- and you can achieve the opposite result."

Monday, November 05, 2007

Gulf States and the Dollar Link

Andrew Critchlow, WSJ:

PEGGED DOWN

• The News: Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, Qatar, Kuwait and Bahrain followed the Fed's decision to cut interest rates by a quarter percentage point.
• Background: The Gulf states' exchange rates are pegged to the dollar, whose decline has diluted the benefit of record oil prices.
• What's Next: Rampant inflation in the region has increased pressure, particularly on the U.A.E., to sever ties with the dollar, which could further add to the dollar's woes.


DUBAI, United Arab Emirates -- Oil-rich Arab sheikdoms, risking new inflation pressure, followed the U.S. Federal Reserve's lead by lowering official interest rates to keep their currencies aligned with the dollar.

Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, Qatar, Kuwait and Bahrain followed the Fed's decision to cut interest rates by a quarter percentage point.

Because their exchange rates are pegged to the dollar in fixed trading ranges, monetary policy in the Persian Gulf states must mirror U.S. moves to avoid pressures from capital drifting to the currency with the most favorable interest rates.

The moves came despite concerns over rampant inflation in the region, which suggest central banks should be raising, instead of lowering, rates. Bankers said the policy conflict is building pressure on the Gulf states to unbind from the dollar.

In European emerging markets, meanwhile, the Central Bank of Iceland raised its key rate 0.45 percentage point to a record 13.75% in an effort to slow annual inflation, running at a 4.5% rate, down closer to its 2.5% target rate. It was the 19th time since 2004 that the Icelandic central bank has raised rates to keep its economy from overheating. The Romanian central bank Wednesday raised its key rate by one-half percentage point to 7.5%, fighting a 6% inflation rate the bank blamed on soaring household income and rising public spending.

In Asia, meanwhile, sharper-than-anticipated consumer-price inflation last month -- 3% above year-earlier levels -- prompted speculation the Bank of Korea will raise its policy rate, now at 5%, in the first quarter next year. The Hong Kong Monetary Authority, also struggling to balance domestic considerations with pressures from overseas investors, has been intervening to keep its currency from rising above publicly set bands.

Nowhere in the Middle East are the strains more acute than in the U.A.E., where investors are betting on a "depegging" of the dirham as domestic inflation pressures increase.

"Speculators are definitely bidding on a depegging, and that's why they're increasing their dirham deposits," Henry Azzam, Middle East chief executive at Deutsche Bank AG, told Zawya Dow Jones Newswires in an interview.

Attracting that money are chances of a quick profit once the peg snaps. Deposits held in the emirates' banks have exceeded one trillion dirhams ($272.3 billion) for the first time, more than is deposited in the region's largest economy, Saudi Arabia, latest central-bank figures show.

"The probability of depegging has increased," said Kamran Butt, Dubai-based chief economist at Credit Suisse Group. "The market consensus is for the U.A.E. to depeg." A decision by the U.A.E. to sever ties with the dollar could alienate the U.S. and add to the dollar's woes at a time of economic uncertainty and record oil prices.

The dollar, which fell to all-time lows against the euro and 26-year lows against sterling in the aftermath of Wednesday's rate cut, was at $1.4437 against the euro, from $1.4486 Wednesday. The U.K. pound was at $2.0787, from $2.0793 Wednesday.

The dollar's slump has pushed up the cost of imports to the Gulf, fueling inflation. The dollar's decline has watered down the benefit of record oil prices in the region that is expected to accrue a surplus in excess of $500 billion this year, according to Saudi lender Samba Financial Group.

Kuwait, the region's third-largest Arab oil producer, was the first to break ranks with its Gulf peers in May when it shunned its peg with the dollar by allowing the dinar to float against a basket of currencies and in a range against the dollar. It retains a loose dollar peg and joined other states in cutting rates yesterday.

The seven emirates are Abu Dhabi, 'Ajman, Al Fujayrah, Sharjah, Dubai, Ra's al Khaymah and Quwayn.

With inflation expected to exceed 10% for a second consecutive year in the U.A.E., the emirates' ruling sheiks face the region's greatest fiscal policy challenge since the U.K. devalued sterling in 1967, forcing Gulf states to turn to the dollar as a benchmark.

When the emirates created the dirham in 1973 they linked it effectively to the dollar. Now bankers such as Deutsche's Mr. Azzam are unsure whether the U.A.E. is ready for another such change. "I don't think a depeg will happen because that's a regional decision and it has served the U.A.E. so far," he said.

Fed Policy and Moral Hazard

Harvey Rosenblum, WSJ:


Accusations of moral hazard have been tossed around quite a bit since the Federal Reserve lowered the federal-funds rate by half a percentage point a month ago today. Moral hazard, if you’re neither an actuary nor a practitioner of the “dismal science,” occurs when investors or property owners are protected from the downside risks of bad investment decisions, thus encouraging them to take still more unwise risks in the future.

[Chart]

As entertaining as this discussion of the nexus between the Federal Reserve and moral hazard has been, the analysis is incomplete because it lacks one key element — something called the Taylor Rule. The namesake of this bit of economic wisdom is John Taylor, perhaps the best scholar on monetary policy in our times. His rule, a description of monetary policy decision-making formulated a decade and a half ago, has a good deal of relevance to any discussion of Fed policy and moral hazard.

So what exactly is Taylor’s Rule? Put simply, it prescribes higher interest rates when inflation crosses certain thresholds and the economy is near full employment; and lower rates when the opposite is true. When these goals are in conflict the Rule provides guidance on how to adjust rates accordingly.

But before we get to why Mr. Taylor’s work matters, we’ve got to better understand moral hazard, which, as Mr. Bernanke defined it in a textbook he coauthored, is “the tendency of people to expend less effort protecting those goods that are insured against theft and damage.”

Why has moral hazard reared its head after the Federal Open Market Committee cut interest rates at a time of turmoil and uncertainty in financial markets? If the FOMC decision has provided an insurance policy that protects investor portfolios against damage, and if investor behavior takes this insurance into account in advance, then the FOMC, I will argue, does create a moral hazard each and every time it makes a monetary policy decision. This proposition is equally true whether the FOMC lowers rates, raises rates, or leaves them unchanged. Moral hazard goes with the territory.

Some writers go a step further and blame the Fed for intentionally creating moral hazard with the “Bernanke put,” an updating of the “Greenspan put.” A “put” cushions an investor against a decline in the price of a security through an option to sell at some specified price before the put’s expiration date. Former Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan’s name was attached to the concept in the mid-1990s, when stock-market investors supposedly began to believe that the FOMC wouldn’t raise the federal-funds target rate to restrain a rising stock market but would lower rates — quickly, vigorously, and intentionally — to stem stock-market declines.

If the Fed practiced such one-sided intervention, stock-market investors would suffer little or no downside risk. Sounds too good to be true and it is, as any investor who rode the roller coaster of the 80% drop in the Nasdaq in 2000-2002 would verify.

Greenspan or Bernanke “puts” make good copy, but they’re at odds with how the FOMC operates. By law, the Fed has a dual mandate to promote maximum employment and price stability. In practice, the FOMC seeks to foster an economic environment characterized by low and steady inflation, a low unemployment rate and a sustainable rate of economic growth. To carry out its mandate, the Fed needs a healthy, smoothly functioning banking and financial system.

After all, this financial infrastructure constitutes the conduit — or plumbing — through which the early actions of monetary policy flow to the rest of the economy. If the flow of money and credit is blocked, the Fed’s ability to achieve its mandates is compromised.

Financial turmoil is an impediment that must be addressed as a prerequisite to achieving the FOMC’s other goals. In a modern, credit-dependent economy like ours, a sharp reduction in the willingness or ability of lenders to grant, extend or renew credit can set off a contraction of economic activity and employment. Imagine the reduced spending in our economy if the electricity went off and we couldn’t use our credit cards for a week.

The Fed’s mandate makes no mention of the stock market, bond market, housing market or any other asset market. But these markets matter for their financial flows and for their psychological and wealth impacts on consumers and businesses. The stock market and other asset markets matter for monetary policy only insofar as they impact consumer and business spending, employment and inflationary pressures.

The Federal Reserve does not conduct monetary policy to influence stock prices, regardless of whether the stock market is rising or falling. The Fed does, however, try to create the macroeconomic stability needed to achieve its mandates — and this is where Mr. Taylor’s work comes in. Over the past couple of decades, the FOMC’s interest-rate behavior has been replicated closely by a forward-looking Taylor Rule, developed by my Dallas Fed colleague Evan Koenig.

Mr. Koenig’s version of the Taylor Rule suggests that the FOMC boost the federal-funds rate by roughly two percentage points if inflation is expected to rise by one percentage point or if the unemployment rate is expected to fall by one percentage point. Other things equal, the FOMC should raise the federal-funds rate by 0.7 percentage points if GDP growth is expected to rise by one percentage point. Without ever taking any account of the stock market or other asset markets, this version of the Taylor Rule, using publicly available forecasts, mimics quite closely the setting of federal-funds rates by the FOMC over the last 20 years.

Over the last two decades, when FOMC actions correlate strongly with a forward-looking Taylor Rule, the economy has been remarkably stable. Inflation has trended down, and recessions, while unavoidable, have been short, mild and infrequent. The chart nearby depicts one measure of the macroeconomic stability tied to the FOMC’s systematic reference to a Taylor-type rule. As the chart clearly points out, because of the Taylor Rule and students of it, the U.S. economy spends a lot less time mired in recession.

To the extent that the FOMC sets the federal-funds target rate in accordance with some form of the Taylor Rule, there is no central-bank “put.” There is, however, a gain in macroeconomic stability, which can be thought of as an insurance policy that reduces the risk of recession for every worker, employer and investor.

If there is any true moral hazard in our economy right now, this is its source: Americans spend, save and invest in the belief that recessions, if they occur, will be short, mild and infrequent. People believe that unemployment is something that happens to someone else. Indeed, the younger generation in the work force has, for all intents and purposes, had almost no experience with the unpleasantness of a recession. To them, it’s just a word that begins with “R” but they cannot define it or describe it. That’s real moral hazard, because it drives their consumption and investment behavior.

So what’s the bottom line? Simply that moral hazard is an inevitable, inescapable and unavoidable byproduct of the FOMC’s provision of macroeconomic stability. The better the FOMC’s job performance, the greater the recession insurance and the moral hazard that accompanies it. And the closer we are to price stability, the fewer resources we need to expend to protect ourselves from the theft of purchasing power that stems from inflation.

So let’s stop the complaints about moral hazard and the “Bernanke put.” Who wants to be the first to volunteer to live in a world like the first quarter of the Fed’s post-World War I history, when the economy was in recession over 40% of the time? There was a lot less moral hazard then, but there was also a far more volatile economy. As long as Taylor’s Rule reigns, Fed easing should be regarded as a macro blessing, not a hazard to be avoided.

Fed Plans Transparency Steps

Greg Ip, WSJ:

Federal Reserve officials are nearing consensus on several steps to make their deliberations more transparent to the public, but are likely to defer one of Chairman Ben Bernanke's longstanding goals: an explicit inflation target.

The centerpiece of their new communications steps would be the release of economic forecasts of policy makers four times a year, instead of the current two times, with additional detail and background... Moreover, the horizon for those forecasts would be extended to three years from two.

The ... Fed had hoped to finalize them by this month. But the fallout of the market turmoil that erupted in August has complicated the agenda of next week's meeting of the policy-making Federal Open Market Committee and it may defer decisions on its communications policy to a later meeting. ...

While the idea of setting an inflation target hasn't been shelved, officials say it needs more discussion. ... For Mr. Bernanke, deferral of an inflation target represents a setback, but he can chalk up a tactical victory for forging a consensus on other steps. ...

At his nomination hearing in 2005, Mr. Bernanke restated his preference for a target while promising "extensive discussion and consultation" and "no precipitate steps." ...

The FOMC as a whole is still not ready to take the step. One concern is that Congress, having taken a more populist turn since Democrats took power in 2006, could perceive a target as subordinating the Fed's responsibility for employment, despite Mr. Bernanke's insistence to the contrary. Another is that officials don't think the current system is broken.

At present, the FOMC meets eight times a year, and at two of its meetings, members submit forecasts for the current and next year on growth, inflation and unemployment that are included in a report to Congress. The "central tendency" of those forecasts -- a range that excludes the extreme projections -- garners the most attention. ...

At present, the post-meeting FOMC statement and the minutes aren't expected to be altered significantly.